The Economic Times daily newspaper is available online now.

    Mindless tinkering with the tax rules must stop

    Synopsis

    Instead of using tax incentives to direct investments to specific products, the list of Section 80C options should have simpler products chosen for their long-term benefits.

    By Uma Shashikant

    The government tinkers with tax every year when it announces the Budget. One year, they announce new bonds with tax-free interest — and then they stop these bonds. Another year, infrastructure bonds enjoy a tax deduction — and soon they are excluded. They offer tax-free interest in savings schemes, then withdraw them, and then bring them back again.

    The less we speak about ill-thought-out schemes such as the RGESS, the better. What is it that lacks in the government’s policy on tax-saving investments? Behavioural economists have pointed out that there are at least three reasons why the simple and righteous path to saving — putting aside small sums of money — does not work for most.

    First, investors make decisions about lump-sum amounts quite differently than for regular small sums. They readily make decisions about the `30 lakh property, and the Rs 1.5 lakh Section 80C investment in January before the tax deadline, but dither about a Rs 5,000 SIP every month. Second, even when they know what is good for them, many investors lack the will to pursue the right path to long-term wealth.

    Many households may worry about retirement but do nothing to secure it with the aid of their financial advisors. Investors need to be persuaded to act. Third, investors need simple and easy to understand frameworks for making decisions. They like thumb rules. They like simplified learning from experience. And, they depend on recommendations of people they trust.

    When the government offers a tax concession for a savings product, the incentive to save increases. Investors like the idea of immediate saving in tax outgo. They do not worry too much about a product’s features if it comes embedded with a tax-saving clause. They find the money to invest in the product to maximise tax savings. They are ready and willing to hear recommendations about such products.

    This creates a positive environment for savings and investing and diverts savings into tax-saving products chosen by the government. It also creates perverse incentives to introduce toxic products under the garb of tax saving instruments. Which is why the government should be careful about what incentives it offers — and how. First, the government must give up a rigid position on how much saving is desirable and, therefore, worthy of incentives. There is a constant clamour for raising the limit under Section 80C.

    The new limit of Rs 1.5 lakh is too high for some one with an annual income of Rs 6 lakh. For someone with a Rs 60 lakh income, it is too small. The limits under this section are controlled in terms of ‘taxhold foregone’ while completely ignoring the benefits of access to long-term funds. When redefined as a percentage of income, the government actually replaces tax revenue with long-term capital for itself, and tax outgo for the investor with long-term investment for building wealth.

    Defining the tax-deductible savings as a percentage of the taxpayer’s income would serve both purposes — adequate savings by households, and adequate capital for the government. Bold measures that alter the direction of cash flows from annual revenue to long-term capital may work much better than fragmented thinking about revenue collection each year.

    Second, the list of products that enjoy tax concessions should be simple, easy to understand, and fairly homogenous in terms of the purpose they serve for both the household and the government. There is little merit in putting 5-year bank deposits and 15-year PPFs in the same list. There is confusion in making interest taxable in some cases and tax free in others.

    There is needless innovation in bringing products such as RGESS that serve no useful purpose. There is irresponsibility in stipulating shorter lock-in periods for long-term investments such as Ulips and ELSS. And, there is no merit in bringing newer products like KVP (Kisan Vikas Patra) when the same post office is offering NSCs. The list under Section 80C is governed by the ill-founded idea of using tax incentives to ‘direct’ investments to specific products. It should instead taxhold a smaller range of simple products, chosen for their long-term benefit.

     
    Each one of them should enable reduction in known investment risks. Including products that ask investors to buy liabilities or equity shares of a specific entity, even a PSU, is irresponsible. Not stipulating performance benchmarks and allowing every PSU, mutual fund and insurer to offer products that attract tax payers’ money, is equally irresponsible. A basket of debt and equity products, each one of them structured in the simplest possible way, either diversified or issued by the government, screened for performance and process, should be in the list.

    This will enable investors to build a portfolio that meets their requirements for returns and risks. Third, there is no overlooking the need for promotion and distribution. Investors are unlikely to make decisions about financial products unless they are exposed to materials that draw their attention to the merits of the product. Such products need to be available with distributors who can help investors buy them. We have tied ourselves in knots trying to impose upon the simple feet-onstreet salesman the imperative to become a financial planner and advisor.

    There are millions in this country, who will provide simple products to investors if all they have to do is sell. Our worries about mis-selling have completely condemned this useful link out of existence or worse, over-incentivised those who stayed. If tax saving products are promoted for their simple features and merit, and compete with one another only on the basis of their suitability to a saver, distributors will be willing to sell them for a lower incentive. We should be able to see them as we see newspaper vendors, who provide the papers of our choice at a low commission to themselves.

    By making the whole financial distribution piece exotic, and requiring everyone to upgrade or perish, what we have created are perverse structures that frontend commissions and pay distributors much more than the actual value they bring to the system. We also create high entry barriers were minimum gatekeeping will do.

    I suggest a simple test: Find out how many taxpayers have a PPF account and ask them why they use a product that is so long term. Changes to rates or reduction and final elimination of commissions have not impacted its popularity. Enough of tinkering please, let us have good sense instead.

    The author is Managing Director, Centre for Investment Education and Learning

    (Your legal guide on estate planning, inheritance, will and more.)

    Download The Economic Times News App to get Daily Market Updates & Live Business News.

    ...more

    (Your legal guide on estate planning, inheritance, will and more.)

    Download The Economic Times News App to get Daily Market Updates & Live Business News.

    ...more
    The Economic Times

    Stories you might be interested in